Steven E. Landsburg - The Armchair Economist
Here you can read online Steven E. Landsburg - The Armchair Economist full text of the book (entire story) in english for free. Download pdf and epub, get meaning, cover and reviews about this ebook. year: 1993, publisher: Free Press, genre: Romance novel. Description of the work, (preface) as well as reviews are available. Best literature library LitArk.com created for fans of good reading and offers a wide selection of genres:
Romance novel
Science fiction
Adventure
Detective
Science
History
Home and family
Prose
Art
Politics
Computer
Non-fiction
Religion
Business
Children
Humor
Choose a favorite category and find really read worthwhile books. Enjoy immersion in the world of imagination, feel the emotions of the characters or learn something new for yourself, make an fascinating discovery.
- Book:The Armchair Economist
- Author:
- Publisher:Free Press
- Genre:
- Year:1993
- Rating:4 / 5
- Favourites:Add to favourites
- Your mark:
- 80
- 1
- 2
- 3
- 4
- 5
The Armchair Economist: summary, description and annotation
We offer to read an annotation, description, summary or preface (depends on what the author of the book "The Armchair Economist" wrote himself). If you haven't found the necessary information about the book — write in the comments, we will try to find it.
The Armchair Economist — read online for free the complete book (whole text) full work
Below is the text of the book, divided by pages. System saving the place of the last page read, allows you to conveniently read the book "The Armchair Economist" online for free, without having to search again every time where you left off. Put a bookmark, and you can go to the page where you finished reading at any time.
Font size:
Interval:
Bookmark:
Notes on Sources
This book contains many ideas and arguments mat I lifted from otherpeople. My memory is not good enough to accurately acknowledge themall. In this appendix I will do the best I can.
: Sam Peltzmans work on auto safety waspublished in the Journal of Political Economy in 1975. Isaac Ehrlichs workon capital punishment was published in the American Economic Review, also in 1975. Ed Learners article on taking the con out of econometricswas published in the American Economic Review in 1983. Theexperiments on rats were reported in several journals including theAmerican Economic Review in 1981.
: The explanation of dressing for success comes from AlanStockman. The riddle about sports betting comes from Ken McLaughlin.Don McCloskey talks about scattering in Markets in History, published bythe Cambridge University Press in 1989.
: The observations about smoking come from apaper by Eric Bond and Keith Crocker in the Journal of Political Economy, 1991. The discussion of why employers give productive fringe benefits isinspired by work of Paul Yakoboski and Ken McLaughlin. The discussionof why we dont buy our jobs (and of how tosplit a check) is inspired by work of Ken McLaughlin. The idea of usingJoseph Conrad to illustrate truth-revelation mechanisms is due to GeneMumy.
: Hanan Jacoby pointed out that sex scandalsneed not be bad for politicians. When I asked him why farmers aresubsidized and grocers are not, Mark Bils responded by asking me whymotel owners are not paid to keep rooms vacant. David Friedman suggestedthe answer.
: The story of the lost dollar bill is a fiction but couldhave been a truth. When I presented David Friedman with the airline ticketconundrum from the end of the chapter, he immediately responded bytelling me that if I believed in an efficiency standard for personal conduct, Iwas honor-bound not to retrieve the next dollar bill that I dropped.
: The entire chapter is inspiredby Ronald Coases article on social cost, published in the Journal of Lawand Economics in 1960.
: James Kahn pointed out to me the irony of Al Gorestiming.
: The observation about Star Markets misleadingadvertising is due to Walter Oi.
: The observation that the possibility of scoops mightjustify either taxing or subsidizing inventors is due to Marvin Goodfriend.The colleague who worries about Styrofoam peanuts is Bruce Hansen.
: I believe, but am not certain, that the idea ofallowing people to sell their punishment rights arose from a conversationwith Alan Stockman.
: Most of the ideas in this chapterare lifted from an article by Walter Oi in the Quarterly Journal ofEconomics in 1971.
: The analysis of polygamy derives from work ofGary Becker. The observation in footnote 3 came from Mark Bils. I learnedthe story about the bargemen from Walter Oi.
: The theory of disappointment is due toJack Hirshleifer. I learned it from Alan Stockman. There is an excellentoverview of auction theory, by R. P. McAfee and. J. McMillan, in theJournal of Economic Literature, 1987.
: This entire chapter is based on original researchthat I have done jointly with James Kahn and Alan Stockman. A paperreporting on that research will appear in the British Journal for thePhilosophy of Science in 1993. Another, more technical paper has beenprovisionally accepted for publication in the Journal of Economic Theory.
: I learned the football analogy from ChuckWhiteman; I believe (but am not certain) that it originated with TomSargent. Milton Friedmans insight that inflation could affectunemployment by fooling people about the real value of their wages comesfrom a paper on the role of monetary policy that appeared in the AmericanEconomic Review in 1968. Lucass work is reported in the Journal ofEconomic Theory in 1972.
Chapter 1
How Seat Belts Kill
Most of economics can be summarized in four words: People respond toincentives. The rest is commentary.
People respond to incentives sounds innocuous enough, and almosteveryone will admit its validity as a general principle. Whatdistinguishes the economist is his insistence on taking theprinciple seriously at all times. I remember the late 1970s andwaiting half an hour to buy a tank of gasoline at a federallycontrolled price. Virtually all economists agreed that if the pricewere allowed to rise freely, people would buy less gasoline. Manynoneconomists believed otherwise. The economists were right: Whenprice controls were lifted, the lines disappeared.
The economists faith in the power of incentives serves him well, andhe trusts it as a guide in unfamiliar territory. In 1965, RalphNader published Unsafe at Any Speed, a book calling attentionto various design elements that made cars more dangerous thannecessary. The federal government soon responded with a wide rangeof automobile safety legislation, mandating the use of seat belts,padded dashboards, collapsible steering columns, dual brakingsystems, and penetration-resistant windshields.
Even before theregulations went into effect, any economist could have predictedone of their consequences: The number of auto accidents increased.The reason is that the threat of being killed in an accident is apowerful incentive to drive carefully. But a driver with a seatbelt and a padded dashboard faces less of a threat. Because peoplerespond to incentives, drivers are less careful. The result is moreaccidents.
The principle I am applying is precisely the same one thatpredicted the disappearance of gasoline lines. When the price ofgasoline is low, people choose to buy more gasoline. When the price ofaccidents (e.g., the probability of being killed or the expectedmedical bill) is low, people choose to have more accidents.
You might object that accidents, unlike gasoline, are not in any sensea good that people would ever choose to purchase. But speed andrecklessness are goods in the sense that people seem to want them.Choosing to drive faster or more recklessly is tantamount tochoosing more accidents, at least in a probabilistic sense.
An interesting question remains. How big is the effect in question?How many additional accidents were caused by the safetyregulations of the 1960s? Here is a striking way to frame thequestion: The regulations tend to reduce the number of driver deathsby making it easier to survive an accident. At the same time, theregulations tend to increase the number of driver deaths byencouraging reckless behavior. Which effect is the greater? Is thenet effect of the regulations to decrease or to increase the numberof driver deaths?
This question cannot be answered by pure logic. One must look atactual numbers. In the middle 1970s, Sam Peltzman of the Universityof Chicago did just that. He found that the two effects were ofapproximately equal size and therefore cancelled each other out.There were more accidents and fewer driver deaths per accident, butthe total number of driver deaths remained essentially unchanged.An interesting side effect appears to have been an increase in thenumber of pedestrian deaths; pedestrians, after all, gain nobenefit from padded dashboards.
I have discovered that when I tell noneconomists about Peltzmansresults, they find it almost impossible to believe that people woulddrive less carefully simply because their cars are safer.Economists, who have learned to respect the principle that peoplerespond to incentives, do not have this problem.
If you find it hard to believe that people drive less carefully whentheir cars are safer, consider the proposition that people drive
Font size:
Interval:
Bookmark:
Similar books «The Armchair Economist»
Look at similar books to The Armchair Economist. We have selected literature similar in name and meaning in the hope of providing readers with more options to find new, interesting, not yet read works.
Discussion, reviews of the book The Armchair Economist and just readers' own opinions. Leave your comments, write what you think about the work, its meaning or the main characters. Specify what exactly you liked and what you didn't like, and why you think so.