• Complain

Edward Conard - The Upside of Inequality: How Good Intentions Undermine the Middle Class

Here you can read online Edward Conard - The Upside of Inequality: How Good Intentions Undermine the Middle Class full text of the book (entire story) in english for free. Download pdf and epub, get meaning, cover and reviews about this ebook. year: 2016, publisher: Penguin US, genre: Politics. Description of the work, (preface) as well as reviews are available. Best literature library LitArk.com created for fans of good reading and offers a wide selection of genres:

Romance novel Science fiction Adventure Detective Science History Home and family Prose Art Politics Computer Non-fiction Religion Business Children Humor

Choose a favorite category and find really read worthwhile books. Enjoy immersion in the world of imagination, feel the emotions of the characters or learn something new for yourself, make an fascinating discovery.

Edward Conard The Upside of Inequality: How Good Intentions Undermine the Middle Class
  • Book:
    The Upside of Inequality: How Good Intentions Undermine the Middle Class
  • Author:
  • Publisher:
    Penguin US
  • Genre:
  • Year:
    2016
  • Rating:
    5 / 5
  • Favourites:
    Add to favourites
  • Your mark:
    • 100
    • 1
    • 2
    • 3
    • 4
    • 5

The Upside of Inequality: How Good Intentions Undermine the Middle Class: summary, description and annotation

We offer to read an annotation, description, summary or preface (depends on what the author of the book "The Upside of Inequality: How Good Intentions Undermine the Middle Class" wrote himself). If you haven't found the necessary information about the book — write in the comments, we will try to find it.

The scourge of Americas economy isnt the success of the 1 percentquite the opposite. The bigger problem is the governments well-meaning but misguided attempt to reduce the payoffs for success.
Four years ago, Edward Conard wrote a controversial bestseller, Unintended Consequences, which set the record straight on the financial crisis of 2008 and explained why U.S. growth was accelerating relative to other high-wage economies. He warned that loose monetary policy would produce neither growth nor inflation, that expansionary fiscal policy would have no lasting benefit on growth in the aftermath of the crisis, and that ill-advised attempts to rein in banking based on misplaced blame would slow an already weak recovery. Unfortunately, he was right.
Now hes back with another provocative argument: that our current obsession with income inequality is misguided and will only slow growth further.
Using fact-based logic, Conard tracks the...

Edward Conard: author's other books


Who wrote The Upside of Inequality: How Good Intentions Undermine the Middle Class? Find out the surname, the name of the author of the book and a list of all author's works by series.

The Upside of Inequality: How Good Intentions Undermine the Middle Class — read online for free the complete book (whole text) full work

Below is the text of the book, divided by pages. System saving the place of the last page read, allows you to conveniently read the book "The Upside of Inequality: How Good Intentions Undermine the Middle Class" online for free, without having to search again every time where you left off. Put a bookmark, and you can go to the page where you finished reading at any time.

Light

Font size:

Reset

Interval:

Bookmark:

Make
Conard provides a much-needed reappraisal of the role of inequality in a free-market economy. The most crucial insight of economics is that incentives matter, and those incentives will inevitably show up as an unequal distribution of economic resources. Conard argues forcefully that the well-intentioned policies of reducing inequality in the short term are not necessarily beneficial in the long term, as inequality and economic growth are closely linked. George J. Borjas , Robert W. Scrivner professor of economics and social policy, Harvard Kennedy School, and author of Labor Economics and Immigration Economics Ed Conard reminds us that inequality sends a signal of what society lacks most; in Americas case, entrepreneurship and risk-taking . That is why it is highly rewarded. Intellectual and political attacks on those who use these attributes will prove to be counterproductive. Lawrence Lindsey , CEO of the Lindsey Group LLC and former director of the National Economic Council In this significant contribution to economic thought , Ed Conard extends our theory that equity and risk-underwriting constrain growth and uses it to identify important consequences for economic policy. Bruce Greenwald , coauthor (with Joseph Stiglitz) of A New Paradigm in Monetary Theory , and Robert Heilbrunn professor of finance, Columbia Business School Economists tend to be enslaved by their models, and too often their work is obscure, unimaginative, and irrelevant. Conards visionary take on the constraints to growth and their effect on inequality is nothing short of revolutionary . Kevin Hassett , resident scholar and director of research for domestic policy, American Enterprise Institute

The Upside of Inequality How Good Intentions Undermine the Middle Class - image 1

For my wife and daughter,
my mother, who died this year,
and my sister, who kept her alive.

The Upside of Inequality How Good Intentions Undermine the Middle Class - image 2

An imprint of Penguin Random House LLC

375 Hudson Street

New York, NY 10014

The Upside of Inequality How Good Intentions Undermine the Middle Class - image 3

Copyright 2016 by Coherent Research Institute, Inc.

Penguin supports copyright. Copyright fuels creativity, encourages diverse voices, promotes free speech, and creates a vibrant culture. Thank you for buying an authorized edition of this book and for complying with copyright laws by not reproducing, scanning, or distributing any part of it in any form without permission. You are supporting writers and allowing Penguin to continue to publish books for every reader.

ISBN 9781595231239 (hardcover)

ISBN 9780698409910 (e-book)

Version_2

CONTENTS

INTRODUCTION

I wrote Unintended Consequences in 2012 because I was concerned that in the aftermath of the financial crisis misguided economic policy would lead to slower-than-necessary growth. The financial crisis had called the value of free enterprise into question in the mind of the public, and I wanted to set the record straight.

The U.S. economy had grown robustly for nearly two decades leading up to the financial crisis. But the U.S. economy ran enormous trade deficits with China, Germany, and Japaneconomies with large surpluses of risk-averse savings. These economies used risk-averse savings to fund large trade surpluses that indirectly necessitated large increases in U.S. borrowing and lendingchiefly subprime mortgagesto maintain full employment. This expansion of credit destabilized U.S. banks. When real estate prices fell 30 percent, it sparked a panicked run on an inherently unstable banking system.

Rather than diagnosing the problems properly, demagogues on the left and right claimed that ill-advised monetary policy, misguided regulation, and debt-fueled growthfraudulently devised by reckless bankershad created unsustainable prosperity. The public bought those views despite two decades of historic U.S. productivity growth that could only have been achieved with hard-earned investment, risk-taking, and innovation.

In Unintended Consequences , I explained why the U.S. economy was gradually growing more productive than Europe and Japannamely, because higher payoffs for successful risk-taking were gradually building U.S. institutional capabilities. More valuable on-the-job training, large synergistic communities of experts, highly motivated and trained talent, and equity in the hands of eager risk-takers had compounding effects on the value of successful risk-taking. I recommended lower marginal tax rates to maintain higher payoffs in the face of slower growth in the aftermath of the financial crisis. The Obama administration did the opposite.

I cautioned that holding the banks responsible for bank runs, instead of just loan losses, at a time when they were already reluctant to lend, would slow growth. I recommended strengthening government guarantees of banks and the Feds ability to function as the lender of last resort but charging banks and borrowers for these guarantees. The Obama administration did the opposite.

Most Keynesian economists insisted that the government need only borrow and spend idle savings to create growing demand. They also claimed that a credible threat of inflation would accelerate growth by discouraging unused savings that slow growth. I predicted that constraints to growth would prevent these policies from having positive long-term effects and that the private sector would dial back risk-taking in response to these policies, slowing growth further. I argued that America should not distort the economy by inflating the money supply to discourage saving nor increase unproductive government borrowing and spending in an effort to put unused risk-averse offshore savings to work. Instead, I recommended that the country should deal with the problem of idle savings directlyby demanding balanced trade with trade partners like China, Germany, and Japan. While trade is critical for growth, trade deficits are not. The Obama administration did the opposite.

To foster growth, the U.S. government borrowed and spent $6 trillion and inflated the money supply four-fold in order to buy another $3 trillion of privately held financial securities. Perhaps the recession would have been worse without these efforts, but eight years after the financial crisis, growth remains anemic and productivity growth has fallen to historic lows. Financial crises likely slow recoveries, but eventually the economy rebounds. No rebound ever materialized, nor is one in sight. Instead, slow productivity growth portends continued difficulties. While its true that institutional capabilities allowed the U.S. economy to recover faster than other high-wage economies, they were already producing faster growth in the two decades prior to the recession.

Because my business partner, Mitt Romney, was running for president when Unintended Consequences was published, the media held up my book as a defense of the 1 percent. At the time, a leading proponent of income redistribution wrote, the biggest surprise, on opening Unintended Consequences , lies in discovering that this book isnt about income inequality at all. The critics demand for a comprehensive defense of income inequality planted the seeds for this book.

Since 2012, accusations that crony capitalism and the success of the 1 percent slow middle- and working-class income growth have only grown louder. While the incomes of the 0.1 percent have soared, the growth of middle-class and working-class incomes has continued to remain slow. Many insist that this gap has grown because the wealthy are rigging a zero-sum game to take what rightly belongs to others. The Upside of Inequality addresses these accusations head-on and explains why income redistribution hurts the middle and working class.

Next page
Light

Font size:

Reset

Interval:

Bookmark:

Make

Similar books «The Upside of Inequality: How Good Intentions Undermine the Middle Class»

Look at similar books to The Upside of Inequality: How Good Intentions Undermine the Middle Class. We have selected literature similar in name and meaning in the hope of providing readers with more options to find new, interesting, not yet read works.


Reviews about «The Upside of Inequality: How Good Intentions Undermine the Middle Class»

Discussion, reviews of the book The Upside of Inequality: How Good Intentions Undermine the Middle Class and just readers' own opinions. Leave your comments, write what you think about the work, its meaning or the main characters. Specify what exactly you liked and what you didn't like, and why you think so.