• Complain

Akerlof George A. - Identity economics how our identities shape our work, wages, and well-being

Here you can read online Akerlof George A. - Identity economics how our identities shape our work, wages, and well-being full text of the book (entire story) in english for free. Download pdf and epub, get meaning, cover and reviews about this ebook. City: Princeton, year: 2010, publisher: Princeton University Press, genre: Politics. Description of the work, (preface) as well as reviews are available. Best literature library LitArk.com created for fans of good reading and offers a wide selection of genres:

Romance novel Science fiction Adventure Detective Science History Home and family Prose Art Politics Computer Non-fiction Religion Business Children Humor

Choose a favorite category and find really read worthwhile books. Enjoy immersion in the world of imagination, feel the emotions of the characters or learn something new for yourself, make an fascinating discovery.

No cover
  • Book:
    Identity economics how our identities shape our work, wages, and well-being
  • Author:
  • Publisher:
    Princeton University Press
  • Genre:
  • Year:
    2010
  • City:
    Princeton
  • Rating:
    3 / 5
  • Favourites:
    Add to favourites
  • Your mark:
    • 60
    • 1
    • 2
    • 3
    • 4
    • 5

Identity economics how our identities shape our work, wages, and well-being: summary, description and annotation

We offer to read an annotation, description, summary or preface (depends on what the author of the book "Identity economics how our identities shape our work, wages, and well-being" wrote himself). If you haven't found the necessary information about the book — write in the comments, we will try to find it.

Identity Economics provides an important and compelling new way to understand human behavior, revealing how our identities--and not just economic incentives--influence our decisions. In 1995, economist Rachel Kranton wrote future Nobel Prize-winner George Akerlof a letter insisting that his most recent paper was wrong. Identity, she argued, was the missing element that would help to explain why people--facing the same economic circumstances--would make different choices. This was the beginning of a fourteen-year collaboration--and of Identity Economics. The authors explain how our conception o.;Introduction -- Identity economics -- Identity and norms in utility -- Where we fit into todays economics -- Identity and the economics of organizations -- Identity and the economics of education -- Gender and work -- Race and minority poverty -- Identity economics and economic methodology -- Conclusion, and five ways identity changes economics.

Akerlof George A.: author's other books


Who wrote Identity economics how our identities shape our work, wages, and well-being? Find out the surname, the name of the author of the book and a list of all author's works by series.

Identity economics how our identities shape our work, wages, and well-being — read online for free the complete book (whole text) full work

Below is the text of the book, divided by pages. System saving the place of the last page read, allows you to conveniently read the book "Identity economics how our identities shape our work, wages, and well-being" online for free, without having to search again every time where you left off. Put a bookmark, and you can go to the page where you finished reading at any time.

Light

Font size:

Reset

Interval:

Bookmark:

Make
Identity Economics A new cadet on left entering West Point salutes the - photo 1

Identity Economics

A new cadet on left entering West Point salutes the cadet in the Red Sash on - photo 2

A new cadet (on left) entering West Point salutes the cadet in the Red Sash (on right) in his company. During Reception Day, the new cadets begin the process of becoming United States Army officers. They undergo administrative processing, are fitted with their initial issue of military clothing, have their hair cut, and start their first lessons in marching, military manners, and discipline.

http://www.westpoint.edu

Identity Economics

HOW OUR IDENTITIES SHAPE OUR
WORK, WAGES, AND WELL-BEING

G EORGE A. A KERLOF
AND
R ACHEL E. K RANTON

Princeton University Press PRINCETON AND OXFORD

Copyright 2010 by Princeton University Press

Published by Princeton University Press, 41 William Street,
Princeton, New Jersey 08540

In the United Kingdom: Princeton University Press,
6 Oxford Street, Woodstock, Oxfordshire OX20 1TW

All Rights Reserved

Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data

Akerlof, George A., 1940

Identity economics : how our identities shape our work, wages, and well-being / George A. Akerlof and Rachel E. Kranton.

p. cm.

Includes bibliographical references and index.

ISBN 978-0-691-14648-5 (hbk. : alk. paper)

1. EconomicsPsychological aspects. 2. Identity (Psychology). 3. EconomicsSocial aspects. I. Kranton, Rachel E. II. Title.

HB74.P8A4944 2010

306.3dc22

2009038216

British Library Cataloging-in-Publication Data is available

This book has been composed in New Baskerville and Syntax by Princeton Editorial Associates, Inc., Scottsdale, Arizona

Printed on acid-free paper.

press.princeton.edu

Printed in the United States of America

10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1

Contents
Part One
Economics and Identity
ONE
Introduction

ANN HOPKINS WAS HIRED in Price Waterhouses Office of Government Services in 1978. By all accounts, she was hardworking and diligent. She retrieved from the discard pile a State Department request for proposals and masterminded it into a contract worth approximately $25 million. But the promotion did not go through.

What was deemed wrong with her performance? Colleagues complained about her deportment and the way she treated her staff. In their written comments on her promotion, the senior partners observed: Needs a course in charm school, macho, and overcompensated for being a woman. Her boss, who supported her, told her that if she wanted to make partner she should walk more femininely, talk more femininely, dress more femininely, wear makeup and jewelry, and have her hair styled.

Price Waterhouse v. Hopkins is an illustration of identity economics at work. The partners were applying contemporary norms for behavior: men were supposed to behave one way, women another. We could interpret these views as reflecting basic tastes or preferencesthey just liked working with women who talked and walked more femininely. But these are not basic tastes such as I like bananas and You like oranges, which are the foundations of the economic theory of trade. Rather, these tastes depend on the social setting and who is interacting with whom. The tastes derive from norms, which we define as the social rules regarding how people should behave in different situations. These rules are sometimes explicit, sometimes implicit, largely internalized, and often deeply held. And the preferences or tastes that derive from these norms are frequently the subject of dispute, so much so thatas in Hopkinsthey may even be adjudicated in court.

This book introduces identity and related norms into economics. The discipline of economics no longer confines itself to questions about consumption and income: economists today also consider a wide variety of noneconomic motives. But identity economics brings in something new. In every social context, people have a notion of who they are, which is associated with beliefs about how they and others are supposed to behave. These notions, as we will see, play important roles in how economies work.

We begin with the Hopkins case because the type of identity involvedthat of genderis so obvious. Even as toddlers, children learn that boys and girls should act differently. But gender, and equally obviously race, are just the clearest manifestations of identity and norms. In this book we study norms in many different contextsin workplaces, homes, and schools.

Origins of Identity Economics

Our work on identity and economics began in 1995, when we were both, by coincidence, based in Washington, DC. We had been together at BerkeleyGeorge as a professor, Rachel as a graduate student. George then went to the Brookings Institution while his wife was serving on the Federal Reserve Board. Rachel was at the University of Maryland.

He had ignored identity, she wrote, and this concept was also critically missing from economics more generally. We decided to meet. Quite possibly, we thought, identity was already captured in the economics of the time; perhaps it was already included in what we call tastes.

We talked for months. We discussed the research of sociologists, anthropologists, psychologists, political scientists, historians, and literary critics. We discussed the focus on identity: how people think they and others should behave; how society teaches them how to behave; and how people are motivated by these views, sometimes to the point of being willing to die for them. We worked to distill many ideas and nuances, to develop a basic definition of identity that could be easily incorporated into economics. And we saw that including identity would have implications for fields as disparate as macroeconomics and the economics of education.

This book builds an economics where tastes vary with social context. Identity and norms bring something new to the representation of tastes. Garden-variety tastes for oranges and bananasto continue with the earlier exampleare commonly viewed as being characteristic of the individual. In contrast, identities and norms derive from the social setting. The incorporation of identity and norms then yields a theory of decision making where social context matters.

This vision of tastes is important because norms are powerful sources of motivation. Norms affect fine-grain decisions of the momentdecisions as trivial as which T-shirt we wear to go jogging. Norms drive life-changing decisions as well: on matters as important as whether to quit school, whether and whom to marry, whether to work, save, invest, retire, and fight wars. We will see throughout the book that identities and norms are easy to observe. Anthropologists and sociologists are professional observers of norms. But norms and identities are also easy to see in day-to-day life. We have already seen two examples: Goldman Sachs, with its fourteen principles, and Price Waterhouse, with the partners descriptions of Hopkins. People express their

Until now, economists have had neither the language nor the analytical apparatus to use such evidence or to describe such norms and motivations. Of course, many economists have suggested related nonmonetary reasons for peoples actions, such as morality, altruism, and concern for status. This book provides both a vocabulary and a unifying analytical framework to study such motives.

Next page
Light

Font size:

Reset

Interval:

Bookmark:

Make

Similar books «Identity economics how our identities shape our work, wages, and well-being»

Look at similar books to Identity economics how our identities shape our work, wages, and well-being. We have selected literature similar in name and meaning in the hope of providing readers with more options to find new, interesting, not yet read works.


Reviews about «Identity economics how our identities shape our work, wages, and well-being»

Discussion, reviews of the book Identity economics how our identities shape our work, wages, and well-being and just readers' own opinions. Leave your comments, write what you think about the work, its meaning or the main characters. Specify what exactly you liked and what you didn't like, and why you think so.