• Complain

Schui - Austerity: the great failure

Here you can read online Schui - Austerity: the great failure full text of the book (entire story) in english for free. Download pdf and epub, get meaning, cover and reviews about this ebook. City: London;New Haven;Conn, year: 2015, publisher: Yale University Press, genre: Politics. Description of the work, (preface) as well as reviews are available. Best literature library LitArk.com created for fans of good reading and offers a wide selection of genres:

Romance novel Science fiction Adventure Detective Science History Home and family Prose Art Politics Computer Non-fiction Religion Business Children Humor

Choose a favorite category and find really read worthwhile books. Enjoy immersion in the world of imagination, feel the emotions of the characters or learn something new for yourself, make an fascinating discovery.

Schui Austerity: the great failure
  • Book:
    Austerity: the great failure
  • Author:
  • Publisher:
    Yale University Press
  • Genre:
  • Year:
    2015
  • City:
    London;New Haven;Conn
  • Rating:
    5 / 5
  • Favourites:
    Add to favourites
  • Your mark:
    • 100
    • 1
    • 2
    • 3
    • 4
    • 5

Austerity: the great failure: summary, description and annotation

We offer to read an annotation, description, summary or preface (depends on what the author of the book "Austerity: the great failure" wrote himself). If you haven't found the necessary information about the book — write in the comments, we will try to find it.

Austerity is at the center of political debates today. Its defenders praise it as a panacea that will prepare the ground for future growth and stability. Critics insist it will precipitate a vicious cycle of economic decline, possibly leading to political collapse. But the notion that abstinence from consumption brings benefits to states, societies, or individuals is hardly new. This book puts the debates of our own day in perspective by exploring the long history of austeritya popular idea that lives on despite a track record of dismal failure.

Florian Schui shows that arguments in favor of austerity wereand are todaymainly based on moral and political considerations, rather than on economic analysis. Unexpectedly, it is the critics of austerity who have framed their arguments in the language of economics. Schui finds that austerity has failed intellectually and in economic terms every time it has been attempted. He examines thinkers who have...

Schui: author's other books


Who wrote Austerity: the great failure? Find out the surname, the name of the author of the book and a list of all author's works by series.

Austerity: the great failure — read online for free the complete book (whole text) full work

Below is the text of the book, divided by pages. System saving the place of the last page read, allows you to conveniently read the book "Austerity: the great failure" online for free, without having to search again every time where you left off. Put a bookmark, and you can go to the page where you finished reading at any time.

Light

Font size:

Reset

Interval:

Bookmark:

Make

Copyright 2014 Florian Schui The right of Florian Schui to be identified as - photo 1

Copyright 2014 Florian Schui The right of Florian Schui to be identified as - photo 2

Copyright 2014 Florian Schui

The right of Florian Schui to be identified as author of this work has been asserted by him in accordance with the Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988.

All rights reserved. This book may not be reproduced in whole or in part, in any form (beyond that copying permitted by Sections 107 and 108 of the U.S. Copyright Law and except by reviewers for the public press) without written permission from the publishers.

For information about this and other Yale University Press publications, please contact:

U.S. Office:

Europe Office:

Set in Janson MT by IDSUK (DataConnection) Ltd

Printed in Great Britain by Gomer Press Ltd, Llandysil, Ceredigion, Wales

Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data

Schui, Florian, 1973

Austerity: the great failure/Florian Schui.

Pages cm

ISBN 978-0-300-20393-6 (cl : alk. paper)

1. Consumption (Economics)History. 2. ThriftinessHistory.

3. Saving and investmentHistory. 4. Economic policy

History. I. Title.

HC79.C6S263 2014

339.47dc23

2013041994

A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library.

10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1

2018 2017 2016 2015 2014

For Cecilia

Contents

Introduction

The austerity policies that have been rolled out in many Western countries have brought all the pain of economic stagnation but hardly any of the promised benefits of debt reduction, renewed growth and prosperity. Nonetheless, support for such measures has remained strong among economists, politicians and substantial parts of the public. How can we explain this steadfastness in the face of economic failure? A way to make sense of this paradox is to place the current debates in historical perspective and look at the deep and ancient roots of arguments for austerity.

For all their topicality, today's controversies over austerity are not new. The notion that individuals, states and societies benefit from limiting their consumption is almost as old as humanity. The term austerity itself goes back to the ancient Greeks, and the question of how much consumption is too much or, indeed, too little was already on the minds of some of the foremost thinkers of antiquity. Since that time, it has remained a focus of political and economic arguments in all ages of Western civilisation, attracting the attention of a rather mixed group of thinkers that included the authors of the Bible, medieval ascetics, enlightened philosophers and modern economists. By reading the current debate as the latest replay of the centuries-old controversy about consumption we can more fully understand the arguments presented by both sides.

Today, the term austerity is often used to denote public spending cuts in general. This captures an important manifestation of austerity policies but it misses their main rationale. Austerity policies are proposed to restore balance in government finances and regain economic dynamism and competitiveness. The former objective is pursued mainly by cutting back on government expenditure that funds individual and collective forms of consumption: for example pensions, health care and education. Where taxes are increased this often leads to a reduction in private incomes and consumption. The second objective, stimulating growth, is mainly sought by lowering the cost of labour, that is, reducing wages and hence individual consumption. Renewed economic dynamism is also expected to result from the reduction of government expenditure and debt: a smaller state is believed to leave more space for private initiative and inspire confidence among private investors and consumers. Austerity policies have many facets but ultimately they are about abstinence from consumption.

Clearly, not all public spending cuts put into place under the label of austerity fall on consumption expenditure. Government spending for investment such as the building of bridges, roads and airports is sometimes reduced, but normally it is protected from cuts or even increased. Expenditure for consumption usually bears the brunt of cuts. This is chiefly because by far the greatest part of government expenditure is for forms of consumption. Any meaningful reduction of government expenditure must therefore mainly reduce these parts of the budget. Moreover, consumption expenditure is also often seen as more dispensable. It is generally accepted that cutting back on infrastructure will damage the prospects of economic recovery and long-term development.

In a similar way, while not all reforms intended to regain economic competitiveness focus on lowering the cost of labour, this is always an essential element. The deregulation of labour markets is mostly geared towards removing laws and institutions that protect workers and union rights and salaries. Labour usually finds itself in a weaker bargaining position in liberalised labour markets. Falling or stagnating wages are often an important result of deregulation. This makes it possible for companies to produce at a lower cost and become more competitive. The inevitable flip-side of this development is that many wage earners lose income and often have to cut back on consumption.

The current controversy about austerity policies is therefore ultimately about the question of whether or not rewards can be expected for abstaining from consumption. In this sense today's exchanges fit into a centuries-old tradition of consumption critique. Indeed, much of the historical commentary on this topic seems oddly familiar when we read it today. To be sure, much has changed since Aristotle, Aquinas and Voltaire pondered similar questions. Political systems were radically different and so were the ways in which societies and individuals satisfied their material needs: it was as normal for Aristotle that a substantial portion of society mainly women and slaves should be excluded from political power as it was for Aquinas that virtually all men and women of his time worked in agriculture and eked out a rather miserable living, without much hope of improvement. And even the much more familiar contexts in which Keynes or Hayek wrote were still different from ours in important respects. Placing the arguments of the past in their own context is therefore crucial to understanding them.

When we review past exchanges about consumption we are bound to encounter unfamiliar vantage points. For the question of how much consumption is right can be approached from many different angles. It is as much a moral, religious or political and even an aesthetic question as it is an economic one. Often the angle from which an author decides to approach the question already predetermines how he or she will answer it.

Today's debates offer a good example of such differences in perspective. The proponents of austerity are often cast as hard-nosed economic experts who advocate unpleasant but necessary measures. The quintessential austerian is the technocrat: the economics professor who turns prime minister in the hour of his country's greatest need, or the experts of the European Commission, the European Central Bank, the International Monetary Fund (IMF), and others who land in a nation's capital to save it from the brink of financial collapse. The considerable power which these experts wield rests primarily on their claim to superior knowledge and understanding of economic matters. Typically they are unelected officials, but large portions of the public support them because they feel safe in the hands of men and women who are well versed in the logic of capitalism and whose vision of the future is not blurred by sentimentalities.

Next page
Light

Font size:

Reset

Interval:

Bookmark:

Make

Similar books «Austerity: the great failure»

Look at similar books to Austerity: the great failure. We have selected literature similar in name and meaning in the hope of providing readers with more options to find new, interesting, not yet read works.


Reviews about «Austerity: the great failure»

Discussion, reviews of the book Austerity: the great failure and just readers' own opinions. Leave your comments, write what you think about the work, its meaning or the main characters. Specify what exactly you liked and what you didn't like, and why you think so.