• Complain

Steven Horwitz - Austrian Economics

Here you can read online Steven Horwitz - Austrian Economics full text of the book (entire story) in english for free. Download pdf and epub, get meaning, cover and reviews about this ebook. year: 2020, publisher: Cato Institute, genre: Politics. Description of the work, (preface) as well as reviews are available. Best literature library LitArk.com created for fans of good reading and offers a wide selection of genres:

Romance novel Science fiction Adventure Detective Science History Home and family Prose Art Politics Computer Non-fiction Religion Business Children Humor

Choose a favorite category and find really read worthwhile books. Enjoy immersion in the world of imagination, feel the emotions of the characters or learn something new for yourself, make an fascinating discovery.

Steven Horwitz Austrian Economics
  • Book:
    Austrian Economics
  • Author:
  • Publisher:
    Cato Institute
  • Genre:
  • Year:
    2020
  • Rating:
    5 / 5
  • Favourites:
    Add to favourites
  • Your mark:
    • 100
    • 1
    • 2
    • 3
    • 4
    • 5

Austrian Economics: summary, description and annotation

We offer to read an annotation, description, summary or preface (depends on what the author of the book "Austrian Economics" wrote himself). If you haven't found the necessary information about the book — write in the comments, we will try to find it.

Steven Horwitz: author's other books


Who wrote Austrian Economics? Find out the surname, the name of the author of the book and a list of all author's works by series.

Austrian Economics — read online for free the complete book (whole text) full work

Below is the text of the book, divided by pages. System saving the place of the last page read, allows you to conveniently read the book "Austrian Economics" online for free, without having to search again every time where you left off. Put a bookmark, and you can go to the page where you finished reading at any time.

Light

Font size:

Reset

Interval:

Bookmark:

Make
Austrian Economics
Austrian Economics
An Introduction
Austrian Economics - image 1
Steven Horwitz

CATO INSTITUTE
WASHINGTON, DC

Copyright 2020 by the Cato Institute.
All rights reserved.

Print ISBN: 978-1-948647-95-3
eBook ISBN: 978-1-948647-96-0

Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data available.

Printed in the United States of America.

CATO INSTITUTE
1000 Massachusetts Avenue, NW
Washington, DC 20001
www.cato.org

CONTENTS
1
Introduction

The Austrian School of economics has received renewed attention in the past few decades as its free-market policy conclusions and association with libertarianism have played a growing role in academic and public debate. This attention became even greater during the housing crisis and the Great Recession, as Austrian ideas were frequently invoked to explain that boom-and-bust cycle. In addition, Ron Pauls campaigns for president in 2008 and 2012 made some of the schools ideas part of the popular political discourse. During the past decade, more young people have been studying the Austrian School as part of their formal college educations, because more economists with PhDs have been trained in that tradition and are themselves teaching at colleges and universities and contributing as public intellectuals to various media outlets.

The increasing public presence of the ideas of the Austrian School might suggest that this approach to economics is something new. However, the truth is otherwise. The Austrian School dates back to the revolution in economic thinking of the 1870s that created the modern approach to economics. At the turn of the 20th century, and for the next few decades, the Austrian School was one of the dominant schools of thought in economics. Its influence was diminished in the 1930s by two developments. First, the Keynesian revolution in macroeconomics that emerged out of the Great Depression pushed Austrian ideas aside. Around the same time, microeconomics was becoming increasingly expressed in formal mathematical terms, with economic problems being seen as special types of engineering problems. Both of these changes in the way economics was done were at odds with the Austrian approach. As a result, the Austrian School all but disappeared from around World War II until the early 1970s.

A second confluence of events, this time in the early 1970s, produced the conditions that led to a revival in the schools intellectual activity and reputation. The combination of high unemployment and high inflation in the early 1970s was not supposed to be possible according to the (broadly) Keynesian economic models in vogue at the time. The failure of mainstream macroeconomics to explain what was happening opened the door to alternative approaches. Two events in 1974, specifically, helped bring the Austrians back into the conversation. First was the awarding of the Nobel Prize in Economics to Friedrich August Hayek for his work on monetary theory and macroeconomics, as well as for his contributions to understanding the informational properties of the price system. All of this work was in the Austrian tradition. Also that year, the Harvard philosopher Robert Nozick published his National Book Awardwinning Anarchy, State, and Utopia, a defense of libertarian political philosophy informed by ideas from the Austrian School. Hayeks Nobel and Nozicks book put discussions of Austrian economics back on the agenda of scholars in a variety of disciplines, in addition to informing public debate.

These events, along with the publication of Israel Kirzners Competition and Entrepreneurship the year before, marked the beginning of a revival of the Austrian School that has continued since, accelerating in the past decade thanks to the inability of the economics discipline to predict and explain the Great Recession. Since the 1970s, the Austrian School has slowly elbowed its way into conversations in the mainstream of economics and is now informing policy analysis and public debate in ways it has not before. Although no reliable data exist, it is almost certain that there have never been more professional economists working in the Austrian tradition than there are today.

The Austrian Schools roots are in the Marginal Revolution in economics that took place in the 1870s. That revolution fundamentally changed the way economists understood the concept of value, which had major consequences for the subject matter and methods of the discipline. Before the 1870s, the value of a good or service was most often explained with reference to the cost of producing it, especially the labor involved in doing so. The labor theory of value was, in one form or another, accepted by almost all major economic thinkers, from Adam Smith to Karl Marx. The theory has a number of obvious problems, including how to reduce different qualities of labor to a single measure and how to explain the value of things that are discovered serendipitously. Early economists worked hard to try to explain their way around these puzzles, much like Ptolemy resorted to inelegant mathematical contrivances to make his geocentric model of the solar system predictively accurate. The ad hoc nature of those explanations created the opportunity for a new systematic explanation of value, which arrived in the form of the Marginal Revolution, the economic equivalent of the Copernican Revolution in astronomy.

In the early 1870s, three thinkers changed the way economics was done by making clear that the value of a good or service was the result of the subjective perceptions of the usefulness to the consumer of the specific amount required for the use at hand (what is known as the marginal amount). Goods did not have intrinsic value, nor were their values determined by the amount of labor or other inputs that had gone into producing them. Instead, goods had value because people thought they were useful, and the specific amount of value they had depended on the particular quantity that was needed to satisfy the users specific want.

Two of those three revolutionaries, William Stanley Jevons in England and Lon Walras in Switzerland, employed a mathematical approach, applying the concept of marginality to model their new conception of utility in terms of simple calculus. By contrast, the third of the three revolutionaries laid out a different understanding of this way of seeing value, stressing more than the other two the subjectivity of economic value and that the margin of choice was determined by the minds of those making choices rather than being an abstract mathematical concept. That third revolutionary was Carl Menger, a professor at the University of Vienna, and the approach to economics he laid out in his Principles of Economics in 1871 became the foundation of what was later termed the Austrian School. In addition to his emphasis on the subjective nature of value, at the center of Mengers economics was human knowledge and the way in which its limits mean that we must constantly deal with uncertainty. For Menger, economics was the study of how humans possessing limited knowledge and facing an uncertain future attempted to improve their well-being by figuring out what they wanted and how best to get it. Mengers vision of economics was very much a human-centered one: man, with his needs and his command of the means to satisfy them, is himself the point at which human economic life both begins and ends. This conception of economics remains at the core of the modern Austrian School.

Mengers other great contribution was to expand and extend the invisible hand concept of Adam Smith. Both in his Principles of Economics and in his later book

Next page
Light

Font size:

Reset

Interval:

Bookmark:

Make

Similar books «Austrian Economics»

Look at similar books to Austrian Economics. We have selected literature similar in name and meaning in the hope of providing readers with more options to find new, interesting, not yet read works.


Reviews about «Austrian Economics»

Discussion, reviews of the book Austrian Economics and just readers' own opinions. Leave your comments, write what you think about the work, its meaning or the main characters. Specify what exactly you liked and what you didn't like, and why you think so.