• Complain

Frank - The economic naturalists field guide : common sense principle for troubled times

Here you can read online Frank - The economic naturalists field guide : common sense principle for troubled times full text of the book (entire story) in english for free. Download pdf and epub, get meaning, cover and reviews about this ebook. City: New York, year: 2009, publisher: Basic Books, genre: Politics. Description of the work, (preface) as well as reviews are available. Best literature library LitArk.com created for fans of good reading and offers a wide selection of genres:

Romance novel Science fiction Adventure Detective Science History Home and family Prose Art Politics Computer Non-fiction Religion Business Children Humor

Choose a favorite category and find really read worthwhile books. Enjoy immersion in the world of imagination, feel the emotions of the characters or learn something new for yourself, make an fascinating discovery.

No cover
  • Book:
    The economic naturalists field guide : common sense principle for troubled times
  • Author:
  • Publisher:
    Basic Books
  • Genre:
  • Year:
    2009
  • City:
    New York
  • Rating:
    4 / 5
  • Favourites:
    Add to favourites
  • Your mark:
    • 80
    • 1
    • 2
    • 3
    • 4
    • 5

The economic naturalists field guide : common sense principle for troubled times: summary, description and annotation

We offer to read an annotation, description, summary or preface (depends on what the author of the book "The economic naturalists field guide : common sense principle for troubled times" wrote himself). If you haven't found the necessary information about the book — write in the comments, we will try to find it.

Presents an analysis of such issues as income distribution, saving, taxation, spending, health care, employment, and financial investment, and explains why they have become problematic under current American economic policies.
Abstract: Ask a dozen talking heads about the course of action we should take to right the economy and youll get thirteen different answers. But what if we possessed a handful of basic principles that could guide our decisions,both the personal ones about how to save and spend but also those national ones that have been capturing the headlines? Robert H. Frank has been illustrating these principles longer and more clearly than anyone else. In The Economic Naturalists Field Guide , he reveals how they play out in Washington, on Wall Street, and in our own lives, covering everything from healthcare to tax policy to everyday decisions about what we do with our money. In todays uncertain economic climate, The Economic Naturalists Field Guide s insights have more bearing than ever on our pocketbooks, policies, and personal happiness. Read more...

Frank: author's other books


Who wrote The economic naturalists field guide : common sense principle for troubled times? Find out the surname, the name of the author of the book and a list of all author's works by series.

The economic naturalists field guide : common sense principle for troubled times — read online for free the complete book (whole text) full work

Below is the text of the book, divided by pages. System saving the place of the last page read, allows you to conveniently read the book "The economic naturalists field guide : common sense principle for troubled times" online for free, without having to search again every time where you left off. Put a bookmark, and you can go to the page where you finished reading at any time.

Light

Font size:

Reset

Interval:

Bookmark:

Make
The economic naturalists field guide common sense principle for troubled times - image 1
Table of Contents

The economic naturalists field guide common sense principle for troubled times - image 2
Introduction
The economic naturalists field guide common sense principle for troubled times - image 3
In an essay written in 1879, Francis Amasa Walker tried to explain why economists tend to be in bad odor amongst real people. Walker, who went on to become the first president of the American Economic Association, argued that it was partly because economists disregard the customs and beliefs that tie individuals to their occupations and locations and lead them to act in ways contrary to the predictions of economic theory.
More than a century later, the general public continues to regard economists with suspicion. My fellow economists often object that this attitude stems from the fact that our positions on many important public policy issues remain poorly understood. Although not the whole story, its a fair point.
For example, economists commonly advocate auctioning rights to discharge atmospheric pollutants, leading critics to bemoan our willingness to let rich firms pollute to their hearts content. The statement betrays a comically naive understanding of the forces that guide corporate behavior.
Firms dont pollute because they take pleasure in fouling the air and water but because clean production processes cost more than dirty ones. Requiring firms to buy pollution permits gives them an incentive to adopt cleaner processes. To avoid buying expensive permits, firms that have access to relatively cheap, clean alternative production methods will be quick to adopt them. A firm will buy pollution permits only if it lacks such alternatives.
Auctioning pollution rights makes sense because it concentrates the burden of pollution reduction in the hands of those who can accomplish it at the lowest cost. It minimizes the total cost of achieving any given air quality targetan outcome that is clearly in the interest of all citizens, rich and poor alike. Evidence suggests that the more people learn about the auction method, the less likely they are to oppose it. For instance, although environmental groups once bitterly opposed pollution permit auctions, they now endorse them enthusiastically.
But misunderstandings of this sort are not the main reason that economists remain in bad odor. There are at least three other important sources of skepticism about my fellow practitioners of the dismal science. One is that our traditional models of human behavior, which emphasize narrow self-interest, strike many as overly cynical. Self-interest is clearly an important human motive, but it isnt the only one. We vote in presidential elections, for example, even though voting entails costs and a single vote has never proved decisive. We leave tips in restaurants we will never visit again. Lost wallets are often returned to their owners with the cash intact. Focusing exclusively on self-interest, in addition to seeming mean-spirited, prevents us from saying anything interesting about an important aspect of human behavior.
A second source of skepticism is that economists traditional models assume, against all evidence, that consumer decisions take place in social isolation. The plain fact is that evaluations of all types depend heavily on social context. For example, the same car that offered brisk acceleration in 1950 would seem sluggish to most drivers today. Similarly, the 3,000-square-foot house that seemed spacious to a corporate executive in 1980 would probably seem cramped today. And the right suit for an interview has always been one that compares favorably with those worn by other applicants for the same job.
Once we acknowledge that context shapes evaluation, many of my professions most cherished propositions go out the window. Traditional models say, for example, that when rational people weigh decisions about how many hours to work each week and how much to spend on various goods, the resulting patterns tend to promote the interests of society as a whole. But thats not true when context matters.
Deciding how much to spend on a suit for an interview is a simple case in point. Experiments demonstrate that a job candidate who is better dressed than others is more likely to get a callback. This creates an obvious incentive to spend more on interview suits. Yet if all applicants tripled their expenditures on suits, the jobs would go to the same ones as before. Under the circumstances, it would be better if everyone spent less on suits and more on, say, preventative medicine and safer cars.
A third source of skepticism about economists is our traditional assumption that people are rational and dispassionate when choosing among various alternatives. Like the assumption that context doesnt matter, this one claims that socially benign results occur when people are free to transact with one another without restrictions. For instance, if someone with a poor credit history agrees to borrow $500 for two weeks from a payday lender at an annual interest rate of 1,000 percent, standard models insist that the state harms both the borrower and the lender if it prevents the transaction.
Since the beginning of recorded human history, however, most societies have seen fit to forbid loan contracts of this sort, ostensibly because people are not nearly as rational and dispassionate as traditional economic models assume. For instance, people often assign insufficient weight to costs and benefits that occur in the future. This makes the benefit of borrowing money seem misleadingly large in relation to the cost of having to repay it, suggesting a clear rationale for usury laws. These laws undoubtedly prevent at least some mutually beneficial transactions from taking place. Yet few societies have embraced economists suggestion to eliminate them. In light of many peoples inability to weigh current benefits against future costs, such bans dont seem mysterious.
In short, much of the widespread skepticism about advice dispensed by economists may be rooted in well-founded misgivings about the wisdom of the advice itself. If traditional economic models rest on inaccurate behavioral assumptions, why should advice predicated on those models be taken seriously?
Recent years have witnessed a revolution in how economists think about human behavior. The emerging field of behavioral economics devoted its earliest efforts to documenting the existence of anomalies that contradict the predictions of rational actor models. More recently, researchers in this field have introduced new models that better describe how people actually behave when confronted with economic choices. In these models, narrow self-interest is no longer the only important human motive, context shapes evaluation, and the consequences of systematic cognitive errors are explicitly taken into account.
Although these innovations have enabled behavioral economists to offer more realistic accounts of how people make economic choices, residual skepticism about economics continues to hamper our efforts to discuss these choices in public forums. Because the predictions made by our traditional models are often wrong, readers tend to discount our arguments even when the models are right. For example, when George Stephanopoulos of ABC News challenged Senator Hillary Clinton to name a single economist who favored her proposal to suspend the federal tax on gasoline in the summer of 2008, she defiantly responded, Im not going to put my lot in with economists! Opinion polls suggested that the senators decision to throw economists under the bus helped inflate her winning margins in the subsequent West Virginia and Kentucky primaries.
Next page
Light

Font size:

Reset

Interval:

Bookmark:

Make

Similar books «The economic naturalists field guide : common sense principle for troubled times»

Look at similar books to The economic naturalists field guide : common sense principle for troubled times. We have selected literature similar in name and meaning in the hope of providing readers with more options to find new, interesting, not yet read works.


Reviews about «The economic naturalists field guide : common sense principle for troubled times»

Discussion, reviews of the book The economic naturalists field guide : common sense principle for troubled times and just readers' own opinions. Leave your comments, write what you think about the work, its meaning or the main characters. Specify what exactly you liked and what you didn't like, and why you think so.