• Complain

Perry G. Mehrling - The Money Interest and the Public Interest: American Monetary Thought, 1920-1970

Here you can read online Perry G. Mehrling - The Money Interest and the Public Interest: American Monetary Thought, 1920-1970 full text of the book (entire story) in english for free. Download pdf and epub, get meaning, cover and reviews about this ebook. year: 1998, publisher: Harvard University Press, genre: Science. Description of the work, (preface) as well as reviews are available. Best literature library LitArk.com created for fans of good reading and offers a wide selection of genres:

Romance novel Science fiction Adventure Detective Science History Home and family Prose Art Politics Computer Non-fiction Religion Business Children Humor

Choose a favorite category and find really read worthwhile books. Enjoy immersion in the world of imagination, feel the emotions of the characters or learn something new for yourself, make an fascinating discovery.

Perry G. Mehrling The Money Interest and the Public Interest: American Monetary Thought, 1920-1970
  • Book:
    The Money Interest and the Public Interest: American Monetary Thought, 1920-1970
  • Author:
  • Publisher:
    Harvard University Press
  • Genre:
  • Year:
    1998
  • Rating:
    5 / 5
  • Favourites:
    Add to favourites
  • Your mark:
    • 100
    • 1
    • 2
    • 3
    • 4
    • 5

The Money Interest and the Public Interest: American Monetary Thought, 1920-1970: summary, description and annotation

We offer to read an annotation, description, summary or preface (depends on what the author of the book "The Money Interest and the Public Interest: American Monetary Thought, 1920-1970" wrote himself). If you haven't found the necessary information about the book — write in the comments, we will try to find it.

The years 1920-1970 saw revolutionary change in the character of the monetary system as a consequence of depression, war, and finally prosperity. The same years saw equally revolutionary change in the character of economic ideas as the rise of statistics, Keynesian economics, and then Walrasian economics transformed the style of economic explanation. The two lines of change reinforced one another, as monetary events posed new questions that required new conceptual approaches, and as monetary ideas suggested possible directions for monetary policy.

Against this background of change, Perry Mehrling tells a story of continuity around the crucial question of the role of money in American democracy, a question associated generally with the Progressive tradition and its legacy, and more particularly with the institutionalist tradition in American economic thought. In this story, which he tells through the ideas and lives of three prominent institutionalists, Allyn Young, Alvin Hansen, and Edward Shaw, progress is measured not by the swings of fashion between two polar traditions of monetary thought--quantity theory and anti-quantity theory--but rather by the success with which each succeeding generation finds its footing on the shifting middle ground between the two extremes.

More than a simple history of monetary doctrine, the book makes a case for the continuing influence of a distinctly American tradition on the evolution of economic thought in general. In this tradition, monetary and financial institutions are shaped by historical forces and adapt to the changing needs of the economy.

Perry G. Mehrling: author's other books


Who wrote The Money Interest and the Public Interest: American Monetary Thought, 1920-1970? Find out the surname, the name of the author of the book and a list of all author's works by series.

The Money Interest and the Public Interest: American Monetary Thought, 1920-1970 — read online for free the complete book (whole text) full work

Below is the text of the book, divided by pages. System saving the place of the last page read, allows you to conveniently read the book "The Money Interest and the Public Interest: American Monetary Thought, 1920-1970" online for free, without having to search again every time where you left off. Put a bookmark, and you can go to the page where you finished reading at any time.

Light

Font size:

Reset

Interval:

Bookmark:

Make
The studies in this series are published under the direction of the Department - photo 1
Picture 2

The studies in this series are published under the direction of the Department of Economics of Harvard University. The department does not assume responsibility for the views expressed.

Picture 3

American Monetary Thought, 1920-1970

Perry G. Mehrling

Picture 4

Picture 5

Picture 6
Picture 7

I Allyn Abbott Young (1876-1929)

II Alvin Harvey Hansen (1887-1975)

III Edward Stone Shaw (1908-1994)

Picture 8

A reader who has already gone so far as to pick up this volume may be presumed to have some curiosity about its advertised subject. A glance at the table of contents, however, is enough to alert the reader that the book is also a series of intellectual biographies of three professors of economics whose names are most likely unknown to the average reader and perhaps even to many professional economists. This preface is intended to allay the reader's fears that the title is false packaging. The hook is indeed about what it says it is about, and the story is indeed told through the biographies of three lives. What then is the link between the two?

As originally conceived, this volume was to be about the development of monetary thought in the United States during the period spanning the intellectual revolution that organized itself around J. M. Keynes' 1936 book, The General Theory of Emplovinent, Interest, and Monev. It was not to he another hook on Keynes, of which there are many and some of very high quality, nor even a book on the American reception of Keynes. Rather I meant to write a hook about American monetary thought more generally, taking as my thence the disappearance of a previously rather vigorous monetary discussion at about the time of the Keynesian revolution and the subsequent "rediscovery of money" in the decades after World War II. My interest in understanding this period stemmed from my personal dissatisfaction with the current state of monetary economics, which led me to search the history of economics for alternative roads not taken.

Though unconventional with respect to my tastes in monetary theory, I was at first quite conventional in my conception of the history of economics as simply the history of doctrine. In trying to understand the ideas of dead economists, however, I found it necessary to understand the minds that had produced those ideas and the problems that had spurred those minds into action. As a consequence, rather than surveying the principal professional publications of famous monetary economists, I found myself reading all the publications, and as much of the unpublished writing as I could find, of a select few economists. My subjects' own writing then led me to read also the hooks and articles that they had admired or detested and to study histories of the economic events they had been trying to understand as contemporaries. Finally, in tracing the intellectual development of each individual mind, I found myself exploring the unfolding of a life and the expression of individual character. In short, I found myself writing biography.

In writing biography, I Laced the problem of selection. Whom to choose? It is clear in retrospect that I was fortunate in my conviction that the way to start the story was with Allyn Young. When it came time to choose a second subject, and then a third, I inspected the list of potentials with an eye for continuing the story that Young's life and work had led nee to tell. Choosing Alvin Hansen, and then Edward Shaw, I came to see that my story had evolved from one of intellectual discontinuity-the disappearance and rediscovery_ of money in economic discourse-into one of continuity. It had become the story of the development of a particular strand of American monetary thought, one with peculiarly American origins in the Wisconsin institutionalist school of Richard T. Ely and John R. Commons. As such, it had become the story of the ever anxious relationship between finance and democracy, the story of the evolving tension between the money interest and the public interest in American life.

Having begun by looking for an alternative to modern monetary orthodoxy, I found that alternative not on the fringe but at the very center of the development of American economics. (Richard Ely was, it should be recalled, a founder of the American Economics Association.) Of course what was once central is today fringe, and therein lies another story, the outline of which is sketched in the Conclusion. Suffice it to say for now what the biographical approach makes clear: that economists who came out of the institutionalist tradition had certain conceptions about the nature of their subject, the research methods appropriate to it, and their own role as economists in society. They did not think of themselves as actors on a world-historical stage (like Keynes), nor as geniuses who by the power of pure thought are able to intuit the eternal laws of the universe (as say, Einstein). They were altogether more humble, more life-size, men who sought to understand the drama unfolding around them and to do their bit toward ensuring a more satisfactory social evolution. They were not, perhaps, Great Economists, and therein lies their interest. For bud ding economists of today, these men provide models of possible lives, just as their works provide models for a possible economics.

In today's world of globally integrated financial markets, the question of the relationship between the money interest and the public interest has become paramount, but economics as a discipline has no answer for the question on everyone's lips. Indeed, economics hardly recognizes the question as falling under its rubric, even as all practicing economists recognize, as citizens, that few questions are more important. Whatever we may teach in our texts, economists know just as well as everybody else that unfettered laissez-faire capitalism is no panacea, and, even more, that it is not even a realistic possibility. What keeps economists silent in the current turmoil is that we also know that market allocation mechanisms are essential to the workings of the complex modern economy and probably also essential to the always perilous maintenance of democratic political forms. The three subjects of this volume knew these truths, and they struggled with the tension between them, but they were not silent. For economists who pick up this volume, its main lesson may therefore he how it is possible to think and speak about what we need to think and speak about. Indeed, the life and work of these three men make clear that this was one of the main lessons they were trying to teach.

Picture 9

In writing this book I have received the greatest help from my three subjects thenmselves, whose writings, both published and unpublished, provide the best window on the working of their minds. My primary method has been to read the lifework and then reflect on the kind of man who could leave such a corpus. For application of this method, I am indebted to the careful preservation efforts of archivists such as Harley Holden at Harvard University and Susan McGrath at the Brookings Institution. Without them, this book would not have been possible.

Next page
Light

Font size:

Reset

Interval:

Bookmark:

Make

Similar books «The Money Interest and the Public Interest: American Monetary Thought, 1920-1970»

Look at similar books to The Money Interest and the Public Interest: American Monetary Thought, 1920-1970. We have selected literature similar in name and meaning in the hope of providing readers with more options to find new, interesting, not yet read works.


Reviews about «The Money Interest and the Public Interest: American Monetary Thought, 1920-1970»

Discussion, reviews of the book The Money Interest and the Public Interest: American Monetary Thought, 1920-1970 and just readers' own opinions. Leave your comments, write what you think about the work, its meaning or the main characters. Specify what exactly you liked and what you didn't like, and why you think so.